透明度与公司治理【外文翻译】.doc
《透明度与公司治理【外文翻译】.doc》由会员分享,可在线阅读,更多相关《透明度与公司治理【外文翻译】.doc(9页珍藏版)》请在三一办公上搜索。
1、Transparency and Corporate GovernanceMaterialSource:http:/www.hbs.edu/units/am/pdf/HWTransparencyJan2007.pdf Author: Benjamin Hamelin1 AbstractAn objective of many proposed corporate governance reforms is increased transparency. This goal has been relatively uncontroversial, as most observers believ
2、e increased transparency to be unambiguously good. We argue that, from a corporate governance perspective, there are likely to be both costs and benefits to increased transparency, leading to an optimum level beyond which increasing transparency lowers profits. This result holds even when there is n
3、o direct cost of increasing transparency and no issue of revealing information to regulators or product-market rivals. We show that reforms that seek to increase transparency can reduce firm profits, raise executive compensation, and inefficiently increase the rate of CEO turnover. We further consid
4、er the possibility that executives will take actions to distort information. We show that executives could have incentives, due to career concerns, to increase transparency and that increases in penalties for distorting information can be profit reducing.2 IntroductionsIn response to recent corporat
5、e governance scandals, governments have responded by adopted a number of regulatory changes. One component of these changes has been increased disclosure requirements. For example, Sarbanes-Oxley(sox), adopted in response to Enron, WorldCom, and other public governance failures, required detailed re
6、porting of off-balance sheet financing and special purpose entities. Additionally, sox increased the penalties to executives for misreporting. The link between governance and transparency is clear in the publics (and regulators) perceptions; transparency was increased for the purpose of improving go
7、vernance.Yet, most academic discussions about transparency have nothing to do with corporate governance. The most commonly discussed benefit of transparency is that it reduces asymmetric information, and hence lowers the cost of trading the firms securities and the firms cost of capital. To offset t
8、his benefit, commentators typically focus on the direct costs of disclosure, as well as the competitive costs arising because the disclosure provides potentially useful information to product-market rivals. While both of these factors are undoubtedly important considerations in firms disclosure deci
9、sions, they are not particularly related to corporate governance.In this paper, we provide a framework for understanding the role of transparency in corporate governance. We analyze the effect that disclosure has on the contractual and monitoring relationship between the board and the CEO. We view t
10、he quality of information the firm discloses as a choice variable that affects the contracts the firm and its managers. Through its impact on corporate governance, higher quality disclosure both provides benefits and imposes costs. The benefits reflect the fact that more accurate information about p
11、erformance allows boards to make better personnel decisions about their executives. The costs arise because executives have to be compensated for the increased risk to their careers implicit in higher disclosure levels, as well as for the incremental costs they incur trying to distort information in
12、 equilibrium. These costs and benefits complement existing explanations for disclosure. Moreover, because they are directly about corporate governance, they are in line with common perceptions of why firms disclose information.We formalize this idea through an extension of Hamelin and Wasatch (1998)
13、 and Hamelins (2005) adaptation of Hailstorms (1999) career-concerns model to consider the question of optimal transparency. Section 2 lays out the basics of this model, in which the company chooses the “quality” of the performance measure that directors use to assess the CEOs ability. In this model
14、, the optimal quality of information for the firm to reveal can be zero, infinite, or a finite positive value depending on the parameters. When we calibrate the model to reflect actual publicly traded large us corporations, we find that the parameters implied by the calibration lead to a finite valu
15、e for optimal disclosure quality. Thus, our analysis suggests that disclosure requirements going beyond this optimal level are likely to have unintended consequences and to reduce value.We evaluate the implications of penalties and incentives that potentially affect the motives of CEOs to distort th
16、e information coming from their firms. Measures that punish exaggerating effort can be effective if they are sufficiently severe to curtail this effort; however, relatively minor penalties can be counterproductive. In addition, incentives for CEOs to improve the accuracy of information can harm shar
17、eholders because such incentives push a CEO to disclose more than the value-maximizing quantity of information.3 Concealing InformationIn light of some recent corporate scandals, one concern is not that executives distort information, but rather that they conceal it. In this subsection, we briefly a
18、ddress what our analysis can say with respect to concealing information. One question is whether the other players know if the CEO has concealed information? If so, then presumably they can punish the CEO for non-disclosure Moreover, if it is common knowledge that the CEO knows the value of signals
19、that he conceals, then an unraveling argument (Grossman, 1981)applies: Whatever the inferred expected value of unrevealed signals is, the CEO will have an incentive to reveal those above that expected value. Hence, the only equilibrium is one in which unrevealed signals are inferred to have the lowe
20、st possible value and the CEO is correspondingly induced to reveal all signals. We predict therefore that concealment is unlikely to be an issue if the other players know what the set of signals is.Suppose, in contrast, that the other players did not know what the complete set of signals was(e.g., t
21、he set varies over time).If the CEO did not know the realized value when he deciding to reveal or conceal a signal, then he would wish to conceal all signals that he could: more signals means a more precise posterior estimate of his ability, which means greater career risk for him. Our model, thus,
22、predicts that when (i) the CEO has discretion over what signals are revealed and (ii) must commit to reveal or conceal prior to learning the value of the signals, he will choose to commit to conceal all signals over which he has discretion.If, instead, the CEO is not committed to a disclosure decisi
23、on prior to learning the value of the signals, then he will be tempted to reveal those that are favorable to him. The other players will infer that they are getting a biased sample and, thus, make a downward adjustment. In this sense, the situation is similar to that of “exaggerating effort. “The de
24、tails of the analysis are, to be sure, different and await future analysis, but our general conclusions will generally hold.4 Discussions and ConclusionMost corporate governance reforms involve increased transparency. Yet, discussions of disclosure generally focus on issues other than governance, su
- 配套讲稿:
如PPT文件的首页显示word图标,表示该PPT已包含配套word讲稿。双击word图标可打开word文档。
- 特殊限制:
部分文档作品中含有的国旗、国徽等图片,仅作为作品整体效果示例展示,禁止商用。设计者仅对作品中独创性部分享有著作权。
- 关 键 词:
- 外文翻译 透明度 公司 治理 外文 翻译
链接地址:https://www.31ppt.com/p-3994362.html